The international dimension of central bank digital currencies: Open research questions (2024)

Nearly 90% of central banks worldwide are weighing the pros and cons of issuing a central bank digital currency (CBDC) (Boar and Wehrling 2021). The ECB launched the investigation phase for a digital euro project over the summer. No decision has been taken as to whether to issue a digital euro.

One of the aspects the ECB is investigating is whether it would be possible to use the digital euro in cross-border contexts, and under which conditions. Many other central banks are also reflecting on whether they would allow non-residents to access their own digital currency – if they decided to introduce one (CPMI et al. 2021).

Decisions about the issuance and design of CBDCs require a careful assessment of the trade-offs between risks and opportunities (e.g. Agur et al. 2021, Bindseil and Panetta 2020, Brunnermeier and Niepelt 2019, Fernández-Villaverde et al.. 2021, Niepelt 2020, Uhlig and Xie 2021). The international dimension makes that assessment more challenging still. So, it is already worth thinking about the implications of the cross-border use of CBDCs.

This is where research can help policy. The literature on the international aspects of CBDCs is still in its infancy. Two sets of research questions are particularly relevant for global macro-financial policy: What is different about CBDCs? And what are their implications for international central bank cooperation?1

What we know

Research points to three main implications of allowing non-residents unrestricted access to a given CBDC.

First, a CBDC that can be used outside the jurisdiction where it is issued might increase the risk of digital currency substitution – or digital ‘dollarisation’ (e.g. Brunnermeier et al. 2021). If a foreign CBDC were to be widely adopted, this might lead to the domestic currency losing its function as a medium of exchange, unit of account and store of value – ultimately impairing the effectiveness of domestic monetary policy and raising financial stability risks. These risks are particularly relevant for emerging markets and less developed economies that have unstable currencies and weak fundamentals. Currency substitution could also occur in small advanced economies open to trade and integrated in global value chains (Ikeda 2020). It is hard to gauge in advance how significant the risks of digital currency substitution could be, and in which currencies this substitution could occur. In any case, according to the (unwritten) code of central banking, the introduction of a CDBC in one jurisdiction must do no harm.2In particular, it must not put the financial system of other jurisdictions at risk.

Second, issuing a CBDC can magnify the cross-border transmission of shocks, increase exchange rate volatility and alter capital flow dynamics. One reason for this is that CBDCs combine characteristics such as scalability, liquidity and (potentially) renumeration, which make them appealing relative to financial assets that are traded internationally. Research finds that introducing a CBDC available to non-residents ‘super charges’ uncovered interest rate parity – the standard relation between interest rate differentials across countries and the exchange rate (Ferrari et al. 2020). That, in turn, leads to a stronger rebalancing of global portfolios in response to shocks, and to higher exchange rate volatility. Economies not issuing a CBDC are then subject to stronger spillovers. And their central banks need to be more reactive to output and inflation fluctuations, which reduces their policy autonomy.

Finally, research suggests that issuing a CBDC which can be used by non-residents might have an impact on the international role of currencies. The costs of cross-border payments might fall, which may enhance the role of a currency as a global payment unit. And the specific features of a CBDC – such as safety, liquidity, efficiency and scalability – might further bolster its international use. But there is a flipside to this: broader international demand may cause the exchange rate to appreciate. This could weigh on the currency’s attractiveness as an invoicing or settlement unit for exports in other jurisdictions and, in turn, reduce global interest in the currency. On the whole, model simulations by ECB staff suggest that issuing a CBDC would support the international role of a currency, albeit not to a particularly large extent (ECB 2021a). In other words, economic fundamentals underpinning international currency use matter more.

What is different about CBDCs?

Existing research often models CBDCs as safe and liquid instruments. That is convenient as it allows us to draw on standard macro-monetary models, with some tweaks here and there. But to truly understand the risks and opportunities of CBDCs, we need to take them more seriously and acquire a deeper understanding of what makes them different from other monetary and financial instruments.

Consider a few examples. First, how much of the discussion on the risks arising from digital dollarisation is new? The determinants emphasised in existing research often seem all too reminiscent of the macro literature of the 1990s on dollarisation. It would be good to understand what is truly unique about CBDCs now as compared with dollarisation back then. For instance, maybe the determinants are unchanged but CBDC makes dollarisation more likely by lowering transaction costs. Or perhaps CBDCs could be bundled with other useful services, such as privacy services, rewards or conditional payments.

Second, on international spillovers, introducing any other internationally traded safe and liquid instrument, such as a highly rated bond, into a macro model would also produce strong spillovers. So, can we truly apply the same insights to CBDCs? We need to make sure we do not miss relevant channels and idiosyncrasies.

Third, concerning the international role of currencies, the effects obtained are likely calibration- or estimation-dependent. Under which conditions will standard economic fundamentals remain the main drivers of international currency status? Research so far indicates that digitalisation does not change anything fundamental. Yet, to what extent would CBDCs still have the potential to affect the configuration of global reserve currencies and the stability of the international monetary system?

International cooperation

Other questions naturally emerge when considering the international context. One such question relates to global cooperation. Allowing non-residents to use a CBDC issued in another jurisdiction may give rise to externalities. How much international cooperation is desirable to internalise them is open to debate.

So far, the academic literature provides limited guidance. But international cooperation offers clear benefits: exchanging information allows us to share our experiences about possible problems and solutions, and find consensus on important economic, financial and regulatory issues of common interest. There might be gains from reflecting on common standards to make CBDC projects interoperable, for instance to move from cross-border use of CBDCs to cross-currency payments between CBDCs. Cooperation is not without costs, however. And the costs increase with the number of central banks involved and with their diverse objectives, legal frameworks, financial structures, mandates and preferences, which would likely be reflected in different CBDC designs.

So the natural question to ask is: How much global cooperation is optimal? One might be tempted to aim for uniform standards for CBDCs – a ‘one size fits all’ approach. But whether meaningful cooperation is possible if conditions differ sharply across countries is unclear. Take privacy – an important design feature of a digital euro that was raised by members of the public and professionals in the public consultation the ECB concluded earlier this year (ECB 2021b). A concrete question is: How could a jurisdiction with stringent requirements on traceability of payments allow cross-currency transactions with a jurisdiction granting higher privacy standards? Privacy is unlikely to be equally important in all regions of the world. And where diverse preferences exist, some stakeholders might not see much merit in enforcing global standards.

Still another point to consider is the existence of strategic interactions – where decisions of one player depend on the actions of the other players – as they can tilt the balance of the benefits and costs of global cooperation. Many countries are simultaneously reflecting on CBDCs. But strategic interactions have not been much studied in the context of CBDCs, and the international dimension even less so.

What the optimal timing of actions is, for instance, is not well understood. It is tempting to see the field of CBDCs as a clean slate at the moment. But this will not last. The countries that have already introduced their own CBDCs, such as the Bahamas, cannot set global standards. This will change if major economies launch their own CBDCs. Can the ‘pioneer’ central banks that have decided – or are deciding – on the design of CBDC based on their own considerations be expected to wait for a consensus to emerge on global standards before moving ahead? The costs and benefits of being the first to issue a digital currency are not well understood either. Is it better to issue a digital currency first – and aim to set standards for others, while putting domestic objectives at risk – than it is to get it right?

This list of open questions is not exhaustive, of course. But by addressing them, research would not only push the frontier of knowledge, it would also provide the conceptual backbone and evidence that could usefully inform future policy decisions on CBDCs.

Authors’ note: The opinions expressed in this column are our own and not necessarily those of the ECB.

References

Agur, I, A Ari and G Dell’Ariccia (2021), “Designing central bank digital currencies”, Journal of Monetary Economics.

Bindseil, U and F Panetta, (2020), “CBDC remuneration in a world with low or negative nominal interest rates”, VoxEU.org, 5 October.

Boar, C and A Wehrling (2021), “Ready, steady, go? – Results of the third BIS survey on central bank digital currency”, BIS Papers, No. 114, January 2021.

Brunnermeier, M K and D Niepelt (2019), “On the equivalence of private and public money”, Journal of Monetary Economics 106: 27-41.

Brunnermeier, M, H James and J P Landau (2021), “Digitalization of money”, BIS Working Papers No. 941.

Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures, BIS Innovation Hub, IMF and World Bank (2021), Central bank digital currencies for cross-border payments, Report to the G20, July.

ECB (2021a), “Central bank digital currency and global currencies”, The international role of the euro, July.

ECB (2021b), “Eurosystem report on the public consultation on a digital euro”, April.

Ferrari, M, A Mehl and L Stracca (2020), “Central bank digital currency in an open economy”, CEPR Discussion Paper 15335.

Fernández-Villaverde, J, D Sanches, L Schilling and H Uhlig (2021), “Central bank digital currency: Central banking for all?”, Review of Economic Dynamics 41: 225-242.

Group of central banks (2020), Central bank digital currencies: foundational principles and core features, Joint report by the Bank of Canada, European Central Bank, Bank of Japan, Sveriges Riksbank, Swiss National Bank, Bank of England, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve and Bank for International Settlements, October.

Ikeda, D (2020), “Digital money as a unit of account and monetary policy in open economies”, Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies No. 20-E-15, Bank of Japan.

Niepelt, D (2020), “Digital money and central bank digital currency: An executive summary”, VoxEU.org, 3 February.

Uhlig, H and T Xie (2021), “Parallel digital currencies and sticky prices”, NBER Working Paper No. 28300.

Endnotes

1There are also technical and policy discussions in international fora on how CBDCs could facilitate cross-border payments through different degrees of integration and cooperation – ranging from basic compatibility with common standards to the establishment of international payment infrastructures – in which the ECB and other central banks are involved.

2This has been stressed, for example, in Group of central banks (2020).

As a seasoned expert in the field of central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) and their international implications, I bring a wealth of knowledge and experience to shed light on the intricate concepts discussed in the provided article. My expertise is substantiated by a comprehensive understanding of the academic literature, key research findings, and ongoing developments in the realm of CBDCs.

The article begins by highlighting the widespread contemplation among central banks globally regarding the issuance of CBDCs. Drawing on Boar and Wehrling (2021), it mentions that nearly 90% of central banks are evaluating the pros and cons of CBDCs. The European Central Bank (ECB) specifically is in the investigation phase for a digital euro project, exploring the potential use of a digital euro in cross-border contexts.

Concepts Discussed in the Article:

1. Trade-offs in CBDC Issuance:

  • The article emphasizes the importance of careful assessment of trade-offs between risks and opportunities in the issuance and design of CBDCs (Agur et al. 2021, Bindseil and Panetta 2020, Brunnermeier and Niepelt 2019).

2. Implications of Non-Resident Access:

  • Allowing non-residents unrestricted access to a CBDC could lead to digital currency substitution, posing risks to domestic monetary policy and financial stability (Brunnermeier et al. 2021).
  • CBDCs may amplify cross-border transmission of shocks, increase exchange rate volatility, and alter capital flow dynamics (Ferrari et al. 2020).
  • The international role of currencies may be affected, with potential impacts on cross-border payments, currency appreciation, and global interest (ECB 2021a).

3. Unique Characteristics of CBDCs:

  • Research often models CBDCs as safe and liquid instruments, but the article calls for a deeper understanding of what truly differentiates CBDCs from other monetary and financial instruments.
  • Questions arise about the uniqueness of CBDCs compared to historical concepts like dollarization in the 1990s.

4. International Cooperation:

  • Allowing non-residents access to a CBDC issued in another jurisdiction may create externalities, raising questions about the optimal level of international cooperation (CPMI et al. 2021).
  • The article notes limited guidance from the academic literature on the desirable extent of global cooperation, discussing potential benefits and costs.

5. Open Questions and Research Agenda:

  • The article concludes with a call for further research to address open questions related to CBDCs, including the optimal timing of actions, global cooperation, and strategic interactions among central banks.

By delving into these concepts, the article provides a nuanced understanding of the challenges and opportunities associated with CBDCs, contributing to the ongoing discourse in this rapidly evolving field.

The international dimension of central bank digital currencies: Open research questions (2024)

FAQs

What are the issues with central bank digital currency? ›

While CBDCs don't offer any unique benefits to the American people, they do pose serious risks to financial privacy and economic freedom. From expanding financial surveillance to destabilizing the financial system, CBDCs could impose enormous costs on U.S. citizens.

What are the key aspects of central bank digital currency and its potential implications? ›

The loss of such convertibility has uncertain implications for the basic trust in the monetary system. CBDCs could therefore potentially serve as a “monetary anchor” for the monetary system—and, by extension, also maintain the ability of the central bank to conduct monetary policy (Panetta, 2021).

Why central banks want to launch digital currencies? ›

Accessibility. A central bank digital currency removes the need for citizens to hold a bank account. Banks often require minimum amounts and charge fees for certain actions. Some banks even go so far as to block money movements for some customers.

What do you need to know about central bank digital currency? ›

A central bank digital currency (CBDC) is a blockchain-based digital form of fiat currency issued and managed by a central bank. As CBDCs are essentially a blockchain-powered version of a country's national currency, CBDCs are automatically considered legal tend and can be used for payments.

What are the pros and cons of central bank digital currency? ›

Pros and cons to CBDCs
ProsCons
More efficient and secure payments.Central banks have complete control.
Allow consumers to use central bank directly.Less privacy for users.
Eliminate risk of a commercial bank collapse.Difficult to attain widespread adoption.
1 more row

What are the disadvantages of central bank digital base money? ›

Possibility of breaching user privacy and creating a surveillance state: Depending on the design of the CBDC system, there is a risk that user privacy could be compromised or that the system could be used for surveillance purposes.

Will digital currency replace cash? ›

Central bank digital currencies (CBDC) can replace physical money, especially in economies where cash deployment is costly, Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund Kristalina Georgieva said during a Wednesday speech.

What are the disadvantages of digital money? ›

Risks of Digital Money

Payment fraud is one significant risk that can be attributed to the increasing use of digital money is payment fraud. Payment fraud can be committed in many forms. However, in general, it includes fraudulent or unauthorized transactions completed by a cybercriminal.

How does digital currency affect the economy? ›

Expanding business hours, making more services available online, and even cutting back on fees for things like international money transfers are all changes we have seen in banking since the adoption of digital currency.

Is central bank digital currency necessary? ›

CBDCs have been suggested to improve the process of cross-border payments, especially where those payments involve exchanges between two respective domestic CBDCs. The increased ease of providing payments from governments to people has been cited.

Do we need central bank digital currency? ›

Central bank digital currencies can improve payment systems as well as financial inclusion—if they are appropriately designed. If not, they could pose risks.

What banks are switching to digital currency? ›

The pilot will test how banks using digital dollar tokens in a common database can speed up payments. Participating banks include BNY Mellon, Citi, HSBC, Mastercard, PNC Bank, TD Bank, Truist, U.S. Bank and Wells Fargo.

What is one advantage of central bank digital currencies? ›

One of the main advantages of CBDCs is that they can provide a secure and reliable means of digital payment and remittance. CBDCs can be used for online and offline transactions and can be integrated into existing payment systems.

Is CBDC good or bad? ›

CBDCs may have some benefits, but their drawbacks are considerable. While they can improve payment efficiency and provide central banks with new monetary policy tools, they raise severe concerns about financial privacy, surveillance and control, financial stability, cybersecurity, and commercial bank disintermediation.

How is digital currency different from central bank digital currency? ›

Financial and Monetary Systems

The main difference between CBDCs and cryptocurrencies is that CBDCs are issued and backed by a central bank, giving consumers guaranteed protection, although some concerns remain around data protection and online privacy.

What are the risks of digital currency? ›

Cryptocurrency Risks
  • Cryptocurrency payments do not come with legal protections. Credit cards and debit cards have legal protections if something goes wrong. ...
  • Cryptocurrency payments typically are not reversible. ...
  • Some information about your transactions will likely be public.

Why are people worried about digital currency? ›

In theory, a digital currency could be programmed to lose value — a form of negative interest — to get people to spend it quickly. Those concerns have penetrated the public's thinking deeply enough to surface in the Republican presidential campaign.

Will central bank digital currency replace cash? ›

Will a U.S. CBDC replace cash or paper currency? The Federal Reserve is committed to ensuring the continued safety and availability of cash and is considering a CBDC as a means to expand safe payment options, not to reduce or replace them.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Geoffrey Lueilwitz

Last Updated:

Views: 6090

Rating: 5 / 5 (80 voted)

Reviews: 87% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Geoffrey Lueilwitz

Birthday: 1997-03-23

Address: 74183 Thomas Course, Port Micheal, OK 55446-1529

Phone: +13408645881558

Job: Global Representative

Hobby: Sailing, Vehicle restoration, Rowing, Ghost hunting, Scrapbooking, Rugby, Board sports

Introduction: My name is Geoffrey Lueilwitz, I am a zealous, encouraging, sparkling, enchanting, graceful, faithful, nice person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.